Research
In 2004, the Nobel Committee awarded Finn E. Kydland and Edward
E. Prescott the Nobel Prize in economics, citing theircontribution to “dynamic
macroeconomics: the time consistencyof economic policy and the driving forces
behind businesscycles.” Kydland, the Henley Professor of Economics at the
University of California at Santa Barbara, was in
Washington,D.C., recently to present a seminar at the IMF Institute. He spokewith
Arvind Subramanian, Division Chief in the IMF’s ResearchDepartment, about
receiving the Nobel Prize and the implications
of his work for the economics profession
.
SUBRAMANIAN: What were you doing when the famous callcame
from the Nobel Committee?
KYDLAND: I was in Norway teaching dynamic macro at the
basic MBA level. A secretary came in, saying that there was a call for me. I
wanted to wait five minutes until the break, but she said, “No. No. They are
quite insistent.” When I answered the phone, there was
someone speaking to me in Swedish. The head of
the Nobel Committee read what seemed to be a prepared statement and said, “Just
so you don’t think this is a joke, I have a couple of people here you know.” He
then put them on the line.
SUBRAMANIAN: There’s no question that your work on
credibilityand commitment has made a huge contribution to economics. But can
credibility and commitment be overdone, as some say is the case with the
European Union’s Stability and Growth Pact? In practice, don’t you need the
right combination of flexibility and commitment?
KYDLAND: Well, there are two aspects. One is that
whatever you commit to ought to be a good policy. It should not be commitment
for its own sake, but commitment to something that benefits the people and the
economy, and generates growth that is close to the highest possible rate. So,
first, the choice of policy has to be wise, but then commitment is indeed
extremely important.
SUBRAMANIAN: How do you feel about charges that the
Stability and Growth Pact is too much of a
straitjacket, that there isn’t enough flexibility to adjust to cyclical
variations?
KYDLAND: Well, that’s not so much criticism of a
commitment mechanism as it is criticism of the policy to which Europe has tried
to commit. And without having studied it in detail, it could very well be that
there isn’t enough leeway in the ability to make the debt fluctuate over the
business cycle. Economists
understand that it’s better to make the debt
fluctuate cyclically than make the tax rates fluctuate cyclically. So some
leeway should be included, but not too little or too much.
SUBRAMANIAN: Let me quote two illustrious economists on
real business cycle theory—one of your two contributions cited by the Nobel
Committee. First, “If
recessions are a rational response to temporary setbacks in productivity, was
the Great Depression really just an extended voluntary holiday?” And,
second, “The theory of the
real business cycle is like the Ptolemaic system that guided ships for
centuriesbut was totally wrong.” The first quoteis by Paul Krugman;
the second is by Larry
Summers. Your response?
KYDLAND: Our work created a framework for addressing
interesting aggregate economic questions. It has become a standard framework. It’s
true that our first paper focused on one particular source of business cycles—namely,
shocks to productivity or aggregate production possibilities, which, if you
interpret it broadly, can include lots of things. But since then, the same
framework has been used to study other sources of business cycles, such as
monetary shocks and taxes.
SUBRAMANIAN: The stress on microfoundations was very valuable,
but people seem less convinced by your explanation that cyclical fluctuations
were caused by fluctuations in productivity.
KYDLAND: They were less convinced and it’s less
important. Though I must say that I haven’t seen anything that really overturns
our finding that roughly two-thirds of the U.S. business cycle can be accounted
for by fluctuations in productivity.
SUBRAMANIAN: But is it fair to say that real business
cycle theory is taken less seriously now—microfoundations apart?
KYDLAND: One thing we have learned is that business
cycles are not that costly to people. The welfare implications are not that big—at
least from normal business cycles. That’s not to say, of course, that governments
can’t implement bad policies and make things much worse. But it may behoove us
to devote more attention to longer-run questions where the benefits
can be really great. As our understanding of economic theory improves and as
computers improve, it is natural to turn our attention to things that matter
over the life cycle, such as social security, immigration, age and wealth distribution,
and so on.
SUBRAMANIAN: What are your current research interests?
KYDLAND: One is country studies. I find it interesting
to work on two quite diverse economies like Argentina and Ireland. Argentina
followed very bad policies for decades. In my Nobel Lecture, I called it the time consistency
disease. The surprising thing about Argentina is that once you put the numbers
into a standard model, the model says that Argentina should have grown much
faster in the 1990s. That suggests, for example, that in spite of the currency
board, Argentina didn’t have credibility among
investors—perhaps because they had been burnt several times before. And
Argentina today has substantially lower capital stock per working-age person
than it had 20 years ago. It’s amazing, and very depressing.
Then you have Ireland, which has been an
incredible success story. One can learn from that as well. Part of it probably has
to do with the long-run aspects of the policy measures they put in place to
encourage capital accumulation.
SUBRAMANIAN: Aren’t there really two distinct things here?
One is the need for countries to pursue credible policies for the future; the
other is that countries are victims of their history. If you have a history of
debt repudiation and expropriation, it’s really difficult to erase that. If you
look at debt-to-GDP ratios in the developing world, India’s is very, very high,
about
80–90 percent. But over the past few years,
interest rates actually have been coming down, even though deficits and debt have
been going up. One explanation is that India has less of a credibility problem;
it does not have a history of repudiating debt, overtly or through inflation,
and markets are willing to cut it more slack. People compare debt to GDP around
the
world, but one shouldn’t do it too
mechanically, because it’s not just about the future, but also about the past.
KYDLAND: That’s
a very good point. India is benefiting from the fact that its past governments haven’t
done
things
similar to what past Argentine governments
have done.
Try Finan